The eclipse of PNG’s eight aims & the false dawn of informality
15 December 2015
LATE in the period of preparation for independence, a genuine Papua New Guinean voice emerged in the colonial legislature when Michael Somare’s Pangu party took power on the eve of self-government in 1972.
A consultant team, the Faber Mission, was tasked to recommend policies for an independent PNG. Keith Hart, originator of the idea of the ‘urban informal sector’, was a member of the visiting team.
Hart observed that economic informality, while emergent in rural areas, was still very largely absent from PNG’s urban areas. The Faber Report placed informality at the heart of its strategies for development, later encapsulated in PNG’s ‘Eight Aims’.
The ‘Eight Aims’ was a set of national goals, described succinctly as requiring ‘self-sufficiency, reduction of social and economic inequalities and economic control in the hands of nationalists’.
The goals were adopted enthusiastically (if only briefly) by the new government and incorporated in modified form into the Constitution as the ‘National Goals and Directive Principles’ (where they remain today as a dead letter).
Among other political projects, the Eight Aims inspired an attempt, ultimately unsuccessful, to ‘formalise the informal’ in the PNG urban economy.
Early positive reaction to the Faber Report among Pangu and its allies may be seen as a reaction by indigenous politicians and intelligentsia, along with an influential coterie of expatriate advisors, against the distributional effects of the policies of ‘accelerated development’ pursued by the colonial administration during the 1960s.
This was a period of rising racial economic inequality, with a declining share of national income flowing to indigenous people, even though their employment levels and real incomes were improving in real terms.
The Faber Report acted as a catalyst, giving point and direction to collective discontents, in which issues of localisation and the ownership and control of business were also elements.
This is not to suggest that enthusiasm excited by the Faber Report was either universal or long sustained, but rather that a particular serendipity marked its timing and reception.
Faber and Hart met the new Cabinet in August 1972, after it had received the Report. The other team members had dropped out by then, for fear ‘that their consultancy careers would be wrecked by [what they viewed as] … the lunacy [we] advocated’.
As Hart recalled, Somare said, “Gentlemen, before you came, we only knew of one model for development. Now we know there are at least two”.
Hart’s account also provided some insight into inter-departmental rivalry in Canberra at the time: ‘The Ministry of External Territories … had been a Country party fiefdom. But, with the help of the Commonwealth Treasury, we found that PNG was a redistributive device for siphoning A$500 million a year from taxpayers to three Australian interest groups: trading oligopolies … civil servants … and [Australian] farmers …’.
The team’s proposals to change this situation encountered opposition: ‘What we proposed in the way of grassroots development linked to an emphasis on the income of nationals’ was seen by a World Bank official as ‘a “racist” deviation from orthodoxy.
“Our proposal to renegotiate the terms of the Bougainville copper mine … upset everyone: the colonial administrators who had arranged a notorious give-away, the operators … [and] the World Bank who believed a contract was a contract, the Department of External Territories and so on.”
It was in this “climate of confrontation” that the team “found itself reduced to two”’. As Hart later learned, the Commonwealth Treasury was “the source of our appointment in the first place”.
Perhaps Treasury had doubted the future political stability of an independent state continuing on the trajectory of accelerated development, courtesy of a minerals boom whose benefits were distributed inequitably.
And perhaps Treasury was not unhappy at the prospect of an increased ‘take’ for PNG, which would ease the new state’s transition from dependence on Australian aid.
The last gasp of ‘accelerated development’, set out in a White Paper, was rebuffed by the PNG Parliament in mid-1972 and thereafter events moved quickly. Tony Voutas (one of Pangu’s founding fathers) recalled that a small working group was deputed by Somare to draw on the Report to work up a draft set of policy aims.
“Quite deliberately”, because of Cabinet’s distrust of the old guard, “there was almost no consultation on these aims with senior [expatriate] public servants.
“By imposing policy guidelines on the public service, the Somare Ministry was democratising government.”
By year’s end the old Administration’s colonial planning office had gone, the platform of Eight Aims based on the Faber Report had been announced, and a new Central Planning Office was gearing up to implement it.
In February the PNG parliament took note of the Report and endorsed the Eight Aims as “the basis for economic planning in the coming years”.
The idea of informality also found its way into the constitution of the new state, in that the National Goals and Directive Principles were drafted with several clauses implying the duty of government to support and encourage informal economic activity.
Before long, however, a degree of ambivalence emerged, reflecting disparate elements within the governing coalition.
It became apparent to Tony Voutas that the Eight Aims were contrary to the entrepreneurial ambitions of some ministers, although their “pseudo-socialistic overtones” continued to be “acceptable at the level of public rhetoric”.
Mark Lynch, Cabinet Secretary 1972-77, believed that “the evolution of the … Eight Aims … was probably the closest the Ministry came to expressing a general ideological stance”. Otherwise, the open contest of ideas was muted by “the unstated knowledge” that Cabinet consensus was “too fragile to withstand deep ideological debate”.
This fragility, and the divergence of opinion at its core, would prove to have negative implications for many objectives based on the Eight Aims, not least the objective of stimulating informal activity.
Much later, Ross Garnaut summed up what happened: “In response to an extraordinary concentration of income and wealth in the hands of a small expatriate community, redistribution of high-income employment and business ownership from expatriates to Papua New Guineans was the one distributional focus of the Eight Point Plan to be pursued vigorously and effectively.” A new domestic inequality replaced the racial inequality of the late colonial period.
For some years from 1973, two members of the coterie, Loraine Blaxter and Peter Fitzpatrick, collaborated to pursue a vigorous campaign for government initiatives to stimulate informal economic activity, and for the removal of a raft of regulatory impediments to it.
In 1973, at the height of enthusiasm for the Faber Report, Michael Somare had announced a thorough review of all current legal restrictions, to make it easier for Papua New Guineans to engage in informal economic activities.
That year the duo prepared papers announcing ‘A New Strategy for Development’ and dealing with a wide range of activities and restrictions.
Activities discussed included liquor trading, passenger motor transport, street trading and marketing, and small scale enterprises.
Blaxter and Fitzpatrick listed a catalogue of impediments to economic informality, including “penetration of expatriates into areas that are normally confined to the informal sector”, “comprehensive domination by expatriate interests of most areas of retailing and services”, and “a plethora of laws” that effectively debarred indigenous participation.
The geographer Croz Walsh later noted that they had “made 38 specific proposals for the development of an informal sector”, but that “none of these proposals … had been implemented by 1983”. He remarked wryly that the informal sector had grown nonetheless, without any government encouragement.
Walsh characterised ‘the Blaxter School’ as having proceeded “from the assumption that major economic changes can be accomplished by decree”. This required “assuming there was the political will”.
But, as we know now, that will never existed, since the ‘fragile consensus’ on the Eight Aims could not overcome the combination of entrenched interests and bureaucratic prejudice — both expatriate and indigenous — arrayed against the informal sector.
One expression of this was a generalised political concern about urban drift, showing itself in periodic motions and resolutions in the legislature — in 1964, 1969, 1971 and 1973 — in which authorities were called upon to take action against urban migrants (to the extent of seeking to institute South African-style pass regulations in 1971).
Even indigenous parliamentarians were so imbued with the colonial idea of the town that they were affronted by the visible manifestations of street informality (as they continue to be in 2015).
Blaxter and Fitzpatrick had engaged in one of the earliest attempts at formalising the informal but this proved fruitless.
The lesson from their failure was that informality, rather than being nurtured, would have to arise in the usual manner — as pushback against the forces of bureaucracy, vested interest and prejudice.
John D Conroy is a visiting fellow at the Crawford School of Public Policy at the Australian National University. This article is extracted from Devpolicy Discussion Paper 45, ‘Informality’s elusive thread: policy debates in late colonial Port Moresby’
Amen
Mi 2ya
Kaikai stap
red/green
wadex...
Posted by: Slim Kaikai | 16 December 2015 at 09:28 PM
Like Paul and, I suspect, virtually all other kiaps, I was entirely unaware of the machinations going in Canberra and Port Moresby in the lead up to independence.
Most of us saw it as our task to encourage what this article calls the "informal economy" through, for example, small scale copra and coffee production, setting up "village stores", promoting cattle raising and so forth.
The people we worked with in rural areas were able to sustain themselves through traditional means but generally had no way to enter the cash economy other than by taking a poorly paid job as an agricultural labourer or similar.
There was, of course, an emergent educated "elite" who held down jobs as teachers, nurses, police, public service clerks and the like, but they were not typically entrepreneurial in outlook.
With the benefit of hindsight, we were trying to create an emergent PNG bourgeoisie with the minimum of resources and not nearly enough time.
Discussions of the type mentioned in this article would have passed over my head at that time and its a fair bet that they passed over the heads of most of the soon to be political elite too.
History suggests that whatever altruistic or socialistic notions Michael Somare et all had very soon transmogrified into an ambition to replace the small group of sometimes wealthy expatriates who had dominated economic policy making up until that time.
This is totally unsurprising: there never was a truly coherent ideological underpinning for Pangu or any other political party.
The simple truth is that the sole unifying ambition was to get rid of the colonial administration, with all its inequities, casual slights and petty restrictions.
That done, the founding fathers then discovered that government for the people, by the people and of the people is much, much harder than it looks.
It is arguable that, amongst other factors, the sheer rapidity of change that occurred post independence, both within PNG and in the wider world, simply overwhelmed a nascent political class that lacked the depth of experience, knowledge and insight to successfully navigate a path to the vision espoused in the eight aims.
In this, they were hardly orphans, as the dismal record of much of the post colonial developing world illustrates all too well.
Only now, 40 years later, are some leaders emerging who appear to have the necessary ideological framework and determination to plan, implement and manage policies specifically aimed to achieve genuine advancement for the majority of Papua New Guineans.
I am thinking of Gary Juffa and those of similar outlook, who have realised that past "leaders" have, with some honourable exceptions, simply swapped a formal and relatively benign colonial regime for an new informal regime, whereby various foreign corporations prey upon PNG like vultures upon a corpse.
Obviously, not all foreign corporations or business people are either corrupt or entirely exploitative in outlook, but enough of them are to constitute a major problem for PNG.
As I have said before, nothing short of a revolution, be it democratic or otherwise, is going to change this.
The first step is for a enough Papua New Guineans to truly see and understand what has happened and to give their support to Gary and others who have shown the will and capacity to challenge the status quo.
Posted by: Chris Overland | 16 December 2015 at 02:18 PM
A brief reading of the above demonstrates to me, who was working with rural PNG people at the time, that there was a total disconnection between what was being waffled in Canberra and what was actually happening in the the bush. That was the same bush where 97% of the PNG people lived.
Clearly some saw this time of Canberra waffle as an opportunity for themselves to take the initiative when it was so clear Canberra had no real idea what to do.
With the benefit of hindsight, both were wrong. Neither group was prepared to talk or listen to those who were working with the vast majority of PNG people or to make a genuine attempt to consult with the PNG people themselves.
The rest is history. Genuine ethical, leaders like Gari Juffa have now got an uphill battle to try and correct the mistakes of the past. Those who contributed to today's problems are either pushing up daisies or sitting back and patting their overstretched abdomens.
Posted by: Paul Oates | 16 December 2015 at 10:00 AM
"I am the betel nut
The daga stick
And the lime pot.
I am the red, red stain..."
Posted by: Michael Dom | 16 December 2015 at 07:45 AM